Former safety researcher & TPM at OpenAI, 2020-24
sjadler
I appreciate the feedback. That’s interesting about the plane vs. car analogy—I tended to think about these analogies in terms of life/casualties, and for whatever reason, describing an internal test-flight didn’t rise to that level for me (and if it’s civilian passengers, that’s an external deployment). I also wanted to convey the idea not just that internal testing could cause external harm, but that you might irreparably breach containment. Anyway, appreciate the explanation, and I hope you enjoyed the post overall!
AI companies’ unmonitored internal AI use poses serious risks
Scaffolding for sure matters, yup!
I think you’re generally correct that the most-capable version hasn’t been created, though there are times where AI companies do have specialized versions for a domain internally, and don’t seem to be testing these anyway. It’s reasonable IMO to think that these might outperform the unspecialized versions.
Daniel said:
Thanks for doing this, I found the chart very helpful! I’m honestly a bit surprised and sad to see that task-specific fine-tuning is still not the norm. Back in 2022 when our team was getting the ball rolling on the whole dangerous capabilities testing / evals agenda, I was like “All of this will be worse than useless if they don’t eventually make fine-tuning an important part of the evals” and everyone was like “yep of course we’ll get there eventually, for now we will do the weaker elicitation techniques.” It is now almost three years later...
The post is now live on Substack, and link-posted to LW:
https://stevenadler.substack.com/p/ai-companies-should-be-safety-testing
AI companies should be safety-testing the most capable versions of their models
I’ve only seen this excerpt, but it seems to me like Jack isn’t just arguing against regulation because it might slow progress—and rather something more like:
“there’s some optimal time to have a safety intervention, and if you do it too early because your timeline bet was wrong, you risk having worse practices at the actually critical time because of backlash”
This seems probably correct to me? I think ideally we’d be able to be cautious early and still win the arguments to be appropriately cautious later too. But empirically, I think it’s fair not to take as a given?
You might find this post interesting and relevant if you haven’t seen it before: https://www.econlib.org/archives/2017/04/iq_with_conscie.html
I’d guess that was “I have a lecture series with her” :-)
I think they mean heuristics for who is ok to dehumanize / treat as “other” or harm
Strong endorse; I was discussing this with Daniel, and my read of various materials is that many labs are still not taking this as seriously as they ought to—working on a post about this, likely up next week!
Very useful post! Thanks for writing it.
is robust to ontological updates
^ I think this might be helped by an example of the sort of ontological update you’d expect might be pretty challenging; I’m not sure that I have the same things in mind as you here
(I imagine one broad example is “What if AI discovers some new law of physics that we’re unaware of”, but it isn’t super clear to me how that specifically collides with value-alignment-y things?)
I appreciate the question you’re asking, to be clear! I’m less familiar with Anthropic’s funding / Dario’s comments, but I don’t think the magnitudes of ask-vs-realizable-value are as far off for OpenAI as your comment suggests?
Eg, If you compare OpenAI’s reported raised at $157B most recently, vs. what its maximum profit-cap likely was in the old (still current afaik) structure.
The comparison gets a little confusing, because it’s been reported that this investment was contingent on for-profit conversion, which does away with the profit cap.
But I definitely don’t think OpenAI’s recent valuation and the prior profit-cap would be magnitudes apart.
(To be clear, I don’t know the specific cap value, but you can estimate it—for instance by analyzing MSFT’s initial funding amount, which is reported to have a 100x capped-profit return, and then adjust for what % of the company you think MSFT got.)
(This also makes sense to me for a company in a very competitive industry, with high regulatory risk, and where companies are reported to still be burning lots and lots of cash.)
If the companies need capital—and I believe that they do—what better option do they have?
I think you’re imagining cash-rich companies choosing to sell portions for dubious reasons, when they could just keep it all for themselves.
But in fact, the companies are burning cash, and to continue operating they need to raise at some valuation, or else not be able to afford the next big training run.
The valuations at which they are raising are, roughly, where supply and demand equilibriate for the amounts of cash that they need in order to continue operating. (Possibly they could raise at higher valuations from taking on less-scrupulous investors, but to date I believe some of the companies have tried to avoid this.)
Interesting material yeah—thanks for sharing! Having played a bunch of these, I think I’d extend this to “being correctly perceived is generally bad for you”—that is, it’s both bad to be a bad liar who’s known as bad, and bad to be good liar who’s known as good (compared to this not being known). For instance, even if you’re a bad liar, it’s useful to you if other players have uncertainty about whether you’re actually a good liar who’s double-bluffing.
I do think the difference between games and real-life may be less about one-time vs repeated interactions, and more about the ability to choose one’s collaborators in general? Vs teammates generally being assigned in the games.
One interesting experience I’ve had, which maybe validates this: I played a lot of One Night Ultimate Werewolf with a mixed-skill group. Compared to other games, ONUW has relatively more ability to choose teammates—because some roles (like doppelgänger or paranormal investigator, or sometimes witch) essentially can choose to join the team of another player.
Suppose Tom was the best player. Over time, more and more players in our group would choose actions that made them more likely to join Tom’s team, which was basically a virtuous cycle for Tom: in a given game, he was relatively more likely to have a larger number of teammates—and # teammates is a strong factor in likelihood of winning.
But, this dynamic would have applied equally in a one-time game I think, provided people knew this about Tom and still had a means of joining his team.
Possibly amusing anecdote: when I was maybe ~6, my dad went on a business trip and very kindly brought home the new Pokémon Silver for me. Only complication was, his trip had been to Japan, and the game was in Japanese (it wasn’t yet released in the US market), and somehow he hadn’t realized this.
I managed to play it reasonably well for a while based on my knowledge of other Pokémon games. But eventually I ran into a person blocking a bridge, who (I presumed) was saying something about what I needed to do before I could advance. But, I didn’t understand what they were saying because it was in Japanese.
I had planned to seek out someone who spoke Japanese, and ask their help translating for me, but unfortunately there was almost nobody in my town who did. And so instead I resolved to learn Japanese—and that’s the story of what led to me becoming fluent at a young age.
(Just kidding—after flailing around a bit with possibly bypasses, I gave up on playing the game until I got the US version.)
To me, this seems consistent with just maximizing shareholder value. … “being the good guys” lets you get the best people at significant discounts.
This is pretty different from my model of what happened with OpenAI or Anthropic—especially the latter, where the founding team left huge equity value on the table by departing (OpenAI’s equity had already appreciated something like 10x between the first MSFT funding round and EOY 2020, when they departed).
And even for Sam and OpenAI, this would seem like a kind of wild strategy for pursuing wealth for someone who already had the network and opportunities he had pre-OpenAI?
Just guessing, but maybe admitting the danger is strategically useful, because it may result in regulations that will hurt the potential competitors more. The regulations often impose fixed costs (such as paying a specialized team which produces paperwork on environmental impacts), which are okay when you are already making millions.
My sense of things is that OpenAI at least appears to be lobbying against regulation moreso than they are lobbying for it?
I don’t think you intended this implication, but I initially read “have been dominating” as negative-valenced!
Just want to say I’ve been really impressed and appreciative with the amount of public posts/discussion from those folks, and it’s encouraged me to do more of my own engagement because I’ve realized how helpful their comments/posts are to me (and so maybe mine likewise for some folks).
What do you mean here by “does not mean anything”?
It seems clear to me that there’s some notion of off-the-record that journalists understand.
This might vary on details, and I agree is probably not legally binding, but it does seem to mean something.