In this case, the problem that needs addressing is the quantity of carbon emitted. Cap and trade addresses that number directly. A carbon tax addresses it indirectly: the gov. has to figure out the right level of tax to get the right level of emission reduction in an open market, and continually play with that number to keep it well calibrated. That seems the level of skill that governments (or anyone for that matter) don’t possess.
the gov. has to figure out the right level of tax to get the right level of emission reduction in an open market, and continually play with that number to keep it well calibrated. That seems the level of skill that governments (or anyone for that matter) don’t possess.
The idea that the government can figure out the right level of emissions to begin with assumes a level of skill that nobody possesses.
Taxes have four major advantages over cap and trade schemes—first, they’re less prone to crony capitalism; preexisting companies don’t get a major advantage over new entries. Second, they don’t disrupt the existing market; you don’t hit a wall in which half the power plants in the country are simultaneously shut down. Third, they allow flexibility. Fourth, they’re incremental; they -continually- encourage reduction of carbon emissions; see Europe where the market for carbon credits has effectively collapsed to see what happens when carbon drops unexpectedly; instead of a smooth reduction as possible, it’s jagged and arbitrary.
Europe where the market for carbon credits has effectively collapsed
Why is this a problem? If the emissions are being reduced, then the gyrations of the carbon credit market are irrelevant. If the prices have collapsed, it means that carbon reduction is turning out to be much easier/cheaper than expected. Yay!
I calculate the cost of this carbon reduction to be $3.3 trillion per year across all of Europe. That’s how much smaller their economy is as a result of the recession for which the drop in CO2 was merely an externality. I’m not sure celebrations are in order.
Some studies (which I don’t have to hand immediately) suggest that the recession was only partially responsible for the reduction.
But the price of carbon still remains irrelevant. As long as the reduction happened, the price could be zero for all the difference it makes. We aren’t trying to punish people for emitting too much carbon, making them pay the moral price of their erroneous ways. We’re simply trying to reduce carbon emissions.
I don’t see any drawback to the price of carbon having collapsed.
If your goal is long-term reduction in CO2 emissions, you’ve introduced market volatility. The goal of any such measure is to reduce CO2 emissions, but the -mechanism- by which it does so is encouraging research into alternatives. If the market is volatile, the value of any such research is called into question; tomorrow it might be valuable, it might be worthless. A tax, by comparison, has a fairly static value. The cap-and-trade measure, through its volatility, increases the risk of investment into reducing carbon emissions; the value of your investment isn’t determined by the degree to which you can reduce carbon, but by the amount of carbon emitted in the market as a whole.
Unless we assume some level of carbon emission is better than no carbon emission, the tax scheme is better.
I don’t think this one is hard. In either case, you have to assume an measurement by which you’re accounting for emissions.
Yes, you won’t exactly hit your targets, but then you adjust the price and move on. We’re talking about accumulations that matter over a period of decades. Consumption varies, but it’s not all over the place.
In this case, the problem that needs addressing is the quantity of carbon emitted. Cap and trade addresses that number directly. A carbon tax addresses it indirectly: the gov. has to figure out the right level of tax to get the right level of emission reduction in an open market, and continually play with that number to keep it well calibrated. That seems the level of skill that governments (or anyone for that matter) don’t possess.
The idea that the government can figure out the right level of emissions to begin with assumes a level of skill that nobody possesses.
Taxes have four major advantages over cap and trade schemes—first, they’re less prone to crony capitalism; preexisting companies don’t get a major advantage over new entries. Second, they don’t disrupt the existing market; you don’t hit a wall in which half the power plants in the country are simultaneously shut down. Third, they allow flexibility. Fourth, they’re incremental; they -continually- encourage reduction of carbon emissions; see Europe where the market for carbon credits has effectively collapsed to see what happens when carbon drops unexpectedly; instead of a smooth reduction as possible, it’s jagged and arbitrary.
Why is this a problem? If the emissions are being reduced, then the gyrations of the carbon credit market are irrelevant. If the prices have collapsed, it means that carbon reduction is turning out to be much easier/cheaper than expected. Yay!
I calculate the cost of this carbon reduction to be $3.3 trillion per year across all of Europe. That’s how much smaller their economy is as a result of the recession for which the drop in CO2 was merely an externality. I’m not sure celebrations are in order.
Some studies (which I don’t have to hand immediately) suggest that the recession was only partially responsible for the reduction.
But the price of carbon still remains irrelevant. As long as the reduction happened, the price could be zero for all the difference it makes. We aren’t trying to punish people for emitting too much carbon, making them pay the moral price of their erroneous ways. We’re simply trying to reduce carbon emissions.
I don’t see any drawback to the price of carbon having collapsed.
If your goal is long-term reduction in CO2 emissions, you’ve introduced market volatility. The goal of any such measure is to reduce CO2 emissions, but the -mechanism- by which it does so is encouraging research into alternatives. If the market is volatile, the value of any such research is called into question; tomorrow it might be valuable, it might be worthless. A tax, by comparison, has a fairly static value. The cap-and-trade measure, through its volatility, increases the risk of investment into reducing carbon emissions; the value of your investment isn’t determined by the degree to which you can reduce carbon, but by the amount of carbon emitted in the market as a whole.
Unless we assume some level of carbon emission is better than no carbon emission, the tax scheme is better.
Yeah, a quota is absolutely inelastic supply, giving wildly erratic price. Pricing incremental emissions gives incremental feedback.
I don’t think this one is hard. In either case, you have to assume an measurement by which you’re accounting for emissions.
Yes, you won’t exactly hit your targets, but then you adjust the price and move on. We’re talking about accumulations that matter over a period of decades. Consumption varies, but it’s not all over the place.